Today: Apr 30, 2025

Effects of monetary policy on labour income: The role of the employer

4 hours ago


How do monetary policy shocks affect workers’ wages and employment? Picco et al. (2021) argue that there is a higher sensitivity of labour incomes to monetary shocks in the bottom part of the income distribution. We study the effects of monetary policy shocks on individual employment and labor income conditioning on the firm characteristics.

In Bobasu and Repele (2025), we use matched employer–employee administrative data from Germany.
Our empirical methodology relies on the seminal contribution of Abowd et al. (1999). We estimate panel fixed effects regressions to explain labour market outcomes in terms of employment and wages. We then augment these regressions to include monetary policy shocks and the characteristics of workers and firms.
And we also control for various macroeconomic indicators such as real GDP, unemployment rate and inflation.

We estimate the effects of a monetary policy shock on individual employment probabilities by firm type. Figure 1 presents the results of the regressions. The point estimates suggest that a surprise tightening of 25 basis points reduces the probability of remaining employed by 0.17% (blue bar in column 1). The yellow bars show the coefficients for firm size and age of the same regression with fixed effects and controls.
At 0.05%, the probability of becoming unemployed if working for a young firm is significantly higher than for an older firm. However, the coefficient for firm size is insignificant (yellow bar in column 2).

Finally, we assess whether this differential effect is the result of a worker component, a firm component, or a combination of the two. To assess this, we introduce a triple interaction term between monetary policy shocks, a firm, and the worker characteristic of interest. Relevant coefficients are shown in the red bars. The interactions between monetary policy and both the firm and worker characteristics are significantly negative. This indicates that the age of a firm and the skills of workers matter independently for the impact of monetary policy on employment probabilities. Nevertheless, while worker skills and firm age are significant independently, the interaction between young firms and low-skilled workers does not seem to induce a significant differential impact of monetary policy on the employment probability, as shown in the last triple interaction coefficient in the red patterned bar. These results suggest that sorting alone cannot fully account for the greater sensitivity of workers’ employment probabilities in young firms to monetary policy shocks.

Our results are consistent with a well-established literature on the subject. Moser et al. (2022) find that initially, within firms, lower-paid workers are more likely to leave employment following an adverse monetary policy induced credit supply shock. Similarly, Coglianese et al. (2021) find that the increase in unemployment following monetary policy tightening is larger for workers at small, young firms.

Figure 1 Impact of monetary policy shocks on employment probabilities by firm type

Contents hide
Notes: Significant coefficients at the 1 and 5 levels are shown in a solid colour, while insignificant coefficients are shown in a patterned colour. Errors are clustered at the individual and firm level. Fixed effects include year, worker, firm, industry and industry with year, and the aggregate control variable is GDP growth interacted with the monetary policy shock measure. Monetary policy shocks are standardised series from Jarociński and Karadi (2020). The regressions coefficients are obtained by interacting the characteristic of interest with the monetary policy shock series, and should be interpreted in relative terms, with the baseline being “large”/ “old” firms. Small is a dummy equal to 1 if the firm employs less than 50 employees in a given year; Young is a dummy equal to 1 if the firm has existed for less than five years; Low Skill is a dummy equal to 1 if the workers’ education level is: no diploma, while the other options would be vocational training or university degree The estimation sample is for 1999-2018.

In the second stage of our analysis, we categorise firms based on size, age, and whether their average wage falls above or below the overall sample average, and we explore how monetary policy affects wages across firm types. Our main finding is that wages at smaller firms are less affected by monetary policy shocks compared with those at larger firms. Our preferred specification – illustrated in Figure 2, column 1 – suggest that a surprise tightening of 25 basis points lowered wages by 1.7%. However, the effects are not homogenous across the different firms. When additional fixed effects and controls are introduced, the model’s explanatory power improves markedly.
This adjustment also diminishes the magnitude of the interaction coefficient, suggesting that part of the monetary policy impact is mediated through firm-specific, worker-specific, industry and regional factors. Results in column 2 indicate that a surprise tightening of 25 basis points decreases wages at small firms by 0.63% less than at large firms, effectively amounting to more than a third of the wage decline observed among workers at larger firms. This result is robust across various industries and regions and holds under a series of sensitivity analyses.
By contrast, firm age is not a relevant dimension of the differing wage responses to monetary policy shocks (see the patterned blue bar in Figure 2, column 3).

Keep exploring EU Venture Capital:  TikTok did not breach employment law by refusing to allow worker injured in car crash to work remotely

Notably, our evidence confirms that firm size independently drives the differential wage response to monetary policy shocks. Even when we incorporate a triple interaction involving monetary policy, worker skills, and firm size – as seen in the yellow bars – the additional term proves statistically insignificant, and our primary coefficient remains virtually unchanged. Although worker skills do contribute to the differential wage response, their effect is roughly half the magnitude of that driven by firm size. Finally, the results also indicate that low-paying firms adjust wages by almost 1% less, a coefficient slightly higher than firm size (see the red bar in Figure 2).

Monetary policy shocks appear to influence wages in an asymmetric manner. Our analysis reveals that wages in larger firms – the baseline category – react about two and a half times more during easing episodes than during tightening episodes.
 

Figure 2 Impact of monetary policy shocks on individual wages by firm type

Source: Authors’ calculations.
Notes: Significant coefficients at the 1 and 5 levels are shown in a solid colour, while insignificant coefficients are shown in a patterned colour. Errors are clustered at the individual and firm level. Fixed effects include year, worker, firm, industry and industry with year, and the aggregate control variable is GDP growth interacted with the monetary policy shock measure. Monetary policy shocks are standardised series from Jarociński and Karadi (2020). The regressions coefficients are obtained by interacting the characteristic of interest with the monetary policy shock series, and should be interpreted in relative terms, with the baseline being “large”/ “old” firms. Small is a dummy equal to 1 if the firm employs less than 50 employees in a given year; Young is a dummy equal to 1 if the firm has existed for less than five years; Low Skill is a dummy equal to 1 if the workers’ education level is: no diploma, while the other options would be vocational training or university degree; Low-paying is a dummy equal to 1 if the firm’s average wage is below the average wages paid by the other firms in the sample. The estimation sample is for 1999-2018.

How do the wages of high and low-paid workers at different firms react to monetary policy shocks?

Next, we present estimated effects based on a quantile regression framework using the two-step procedure from Borgen et al. (2021). These highlight potential non-linearities in the transmission of monetary policy shocks to wages. Figure 3 shows our baseline estimated elasticities for firm size, estimated on various percentiles of the wage distribution. Interestingly, the effect is only significant for median and above-median earners – there is no difference between the responses of wages in small and large firms for the lowest-paid quartile of the wage distribution. This suggests that, following a monetary policy shock, large firms adjust their wages more as suggested from the results in Figure 2, but for high-earning workers only.

Keep exploring EU Venture Capital:  Standard Premium Finance Holdings, Inc. Announces Execution of Employment Agreements with CEO and CFO

Figure 3 Impact on individual wages of monetary policy shocks by firm size (percent)

Sources: Authors’ calculations.
Notes: Confidence bands are set at 95%. Errors are clustered at the individual and firm level. Standard errors are obtained by bootstrapping with 50 repetitions. Monetary policy shocks are standardised series from Jarociński and Karadi (2020). S_(j,t-1)is a dummy equal to 1 if the firm employs less than 50 employees in a given year. The estimation sample is for 1999-2018.

Differential pass-through of shocks to wages at different firms

Our results so far indicate that large firms adjust their wages more following monetary policy shocks, especially for their high-paid workers. We try to shed light on the reasons for this. In particular, we look at whether this is because larger firms are more affected by monetary policy shocks than their smaller counterparts, or because their pass-through of shocks to wages is higher.

Figure 4 presents the results for the effects of monetary policy on investment (column 1), turnover (column 2), and wages (column 3). The results indicate no significant difference between small and large firms in terms of the impact of monetary policy shocks on investment and turnover – this is made clear by columns 1 and 2. This indicates that our baseline results do not come from heterogeneous exposure of small and large firms to monetary policy shocks. Instead, column 3 shows that small and large firms adjust their wage bills differently; small firms appear to decrease wages less than larger firms.

Figure 4 Heterogeneous pass-through of monetary policy shocks across small and large firms

Keep exploring EU Venture Capital:  Rona cut dozens of jobs in March due to Canada-U.S. trade war: Reports
Sources: Authors’ calculations.
Notes: Significant coefficients at the 1 and 5 levels are shown in a solid colour, while insignificant coefficients are shown in a patterned colour. Errors are clustered at the firm level. Monetary policy shocks are standardised series from Jarociński and Karadi (2020). The regressions coefficients are obtained by interacting the characteristic of interest with the monetary policy shock series, and should be interpreted in relative terms, with the baseline being “large”/ “old” firms. Small is a dummy equal to 1 if the firm employs less than 50 employees in a given year. In column 1 the dependent variable is real total investment, in column 2 it is real turnover and in column 3 it is total real wages. The estimation sample is for 1999-2018.

Conclusions

Our analysis sheds light on the role firms play in determining workers’ employment and wages responses following monetary policy shocks. We use administrative data that provide employment statistics for a representative sample of German workers and their employers. We find that monetary policy interventions affect the employment of workers at young firms more than that of those at older firms. Additionally, wage adjustments differ by firm size: workers at larger firms experience more significant changes compared with those at smaller firms. Notably, these effects are asymmetric, with wages reacting more strongly during easing episodes than tightening ones, consistent with the existence of downward wage rigidity, and the disparity between large and small firms becoming even more pronounced during periods of easing.
Overall, our results highlight the importance of considering both the wage and employment margins of firms’ adjustment to monetary policy shocks, as these dynamics directly influence households’ consumption and welfare behaviour and can have important distributional consequences.

Authors’ Note: This column first appeared as a Research Bulletin of the European Central Bank. The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments from Alexandra Buist, Jonathan Drake, Alexander Popov, and Zoe Sprokel. For the forthcoming ECB Working Paper underlying this article, the authors are particularly thankful to Maarten Dossche, Beatrice Pierluigi, Jirka Slacalek, Antonella Trigari and Thomas Warmedinger. The views expressed here are those of the author and do not necessarily represent the views of the European Central Bank or the Eurosystem.

References

Bobasu, A and A Repele (2025), “Effects of monetary policy on labour income: the role of the employer”, ECB Working Paper Series No. 3046.

Borgen, N T, A Haupt and Ø N Wiborg (2021), “A new framework for estimation of unconditional quantile treatment effects: The residualized quantile regression (RQR) model”, SocArXiv 42gcb, Center for Open Science.

Coglianese, J, M Olsson and C Patterson (2023), “Monetary policy and the labour market: a quasi-experiment in Sweden”, University of Chicago, Becker Friedman Institute for Economics Working Paper No. 2023-123.

Di Maggio, M, A Kermani, R Ramcharan, V Yao and E Yu (2022), “The pass-through of uncertainty shocks to households”, Journal of Financial Economics 145(1): 85-104.

Faia, E and V Pezone (2019), “Monetary Policy and the Cost of Heterogeneous Wage Rigidity: Evidence from the Stock Market”, VoxEU.org, 12 March.

Jarociński, M and P Karadi (2020), “Deconstructing monetary policy surprises—the role of information shocks”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 12(2): 1-43.

Marotzke, P, R Anderton, A Bairrao, C Berson and P Toth (2016), “Wage adjustment and employment in Europe”, Globalisation and Labour Markets research paper series, University of Nottingham.

Moser, C, F Saidi, B Wirth and S Wolter (2022), “Credit Supply, Firms, and Earnings Inequality”, CEPR Discussion Papers, No. 16123.

Picco, A R, T Jansson, M Klein and N Amberg (2021), “The rich, the poor, and the others: How monetary policy affects the distribution of income”, VoxEU.org, 23 May.



Source link

EU Venture Capital

EU Venture Capital is a premier platform providing in-depth insights, funding opportunities, and market analysis for the European startup ecosystem. Wholly owned by EU Startup News, it connects entrepreneurs, investors, and industry professionals with the latest trends, expert resources, and exclusive reports in venture capital.

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published.